-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 1
/
Copy pathbgrowth2.tex
1463 lines (1250 loc) · 66.2 KB
/
bgrowth2.tex
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
415
416
417
418
419
420
421
422
423
424
425
426
427
428
429
430
431
432
433
434
435
436
437
438
439
440
441
442
443
444
445
446
447
448
449
450
451
452
453
454
455
456
457
458
459
460
461
462
463
464
465
466
467
468
469
470
471
472
473
474
475
476
477
478
479
480
481
482
483
484
485
486
487
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
518
519
520
521
522
523
524
525
526
527
528
529
530
531
532
533
534
535
536
537
538
539
540
541
542
543
544
545
546
547
548
549
550
551
552
553
554
555
556
557
558
559
560
561
562
563
564
565
566
567
568
569
570
571
572
573
574
575
576
577
578
579
580
581
582
583
584
585
586
587
588
589
590
591
592
593
594
595
596
597
598
599
600
601
602
603
604
605
606
607
608
609
610
611
612
613
614
615
616
617
618
619
620
621
622
623
624
625
626
627
628
629
630
631
632
633
634
635
636
637
638
639
640
641
642
643
644
645
646
647
648
649
650
651
652
653
654
655
656
657
658
659
660
661
662
663
664
665
666
667
668
669
670
671
672
673
674
675
676
677
678
679
680
681
682
683
684
685
686
687
688
689
690
691
692
693
694
695
696
697
698
699
700
701
702
703
704
705
706
707
708
709
710
711
712
713
714
715
716
717
718
719
720
721
722
723
724
725
726
727
728
729
730
731
732
733
734
735
736
737
738
739
740
741
742
743
744
745
746
747
748
749
750
751
752
753
754
755
756
757
758
759
760
761
762
763
764
765
766
767
768
769
770
771
772
773
774
775
776
777
778
779
780
781
782
783
784
785
786
787
788
789
790
791
792
793
794
795
796
797
798
799
800
801
802
803
804
805
806
807
808
809
810
811
812
813
814
815
816
817
818
819
820
821
822
823
824
825
826
827
828
829
830
831
832
833
834
835
836
837
838
839
840
841
842
843
844
845
846
847
848
849
850
851
852
853
854
855
856
857
858
859
860
861
862
863
864
865
866
867
868
869
870
871
872
873
874
875
876
877
878
879
880
881
882
883
884
885
886
887
888
889
890
891
892
893
894
895
896
897
898
899
900
901
902
903
904
905
906
907
908
909
910
911
912
913
914
915
916
917
918
919
920
921
922
923
924
925
926
927
928
929
930
931
932
933
934
935
936
937
938
939
940
941
942
943
944
945
946
947
948
949
950
951
952
953
954
955
956
957
958
959
960
961
962
963
964
965
966
967
968
969
970
971
972
973
974
975
976
977
978
979
980
981
982
983
984
985
986
987
988
989
990
991
992
993
994
995
996
997
998
999
1000
% Note to Tom: Must fix the parenthesis and brackets in the expression
% for the Lagrangian. Here texsis is causing problems. Ask Francois.
% See marker below
%\input texsis
%\book
%\input robustin
%\input grafinp3
%\input grafinput8
%\input psfig
%\eqnotracetrue
%\showchaptIDtrue
%\def\@chaptID{4.}
%\eqnotracetrue
%\hbox{}
\def\sumst{{\sum_{t=0}^\infty \sum_{s^t}}}
\def\Ast{{A_t(s^t)}}
\def\cst{{c_t(s^t)}}
\def\kst{{k_t(s^{t-1})}}
\def\kstone{{k_{t+1}(s^t)}}
\def\nst{{n_t(s^t)}}
\def\xst{{x_t(s^t)}}
\def\qst{{q_t^0(s^t)}}
\def\qstone{{q_{t-1}^0(s^{t-1})}}
\def\wst{{w_t^0(s^t)}}
\def\rst{{r_t^0(s^t)}}
\def\rstilde{{r_t^0(\tilde s^t)}}
\def\pist{{\pi_t(s^t)}}
\def\must{{\mu_t(s^t)}}
\def\mustone{{\mu_{t+1}(s^{t+1})}}
\def\thetast{{\theta_{t}(s^{t})}}
\def\thetastilde{{\theta_{t}(\tilde s^{t})}}
\def\thetastone{{\theta_{t-1}(s^{t-1})}}
\def\lhake{{\Bigl[}}
\chapter{Recursive Competitive Equilibrium: II\label{growth1}}
\footnum=0
\section{Endogenous aggregate state variable} %%Introduction}
For pure endowment stochastic economies, chapter \use{recurge} described
two types of competitive equilibria, one in the style of Arrow and Debreu
with markets that convene
at time $0$ and trade
a complete set of history-contingent securities, another with markets
that meet each period and trade a complete set
of one-period-ahead state-contingent securities called Arrow
securities. Though their price systems and trading protocols
differ, both types of equilibria support identical
equilibrium allocations.
Chapter \use{recurge} described how to transform the Arrow-Debreu price
system into one for pricing Arrow securities.
The key
step in transforming an equilibrium with time $0$ trading into one
with sequential trading was to account for how individuals' wealth
evolve as time passes in a time $0$ trading economy.
In a time $0$ trading economy, individuals do not make any
trades other than those executed in period $0$, but the present
value of those portfolios change as time passes and as uncertainty gets
resolved.
So in period $t$ after some history $s^t$, we used the Arrow-Debreu
prices to compute the value of an individual's purchased
claims to current and future goods net of his outstanding liabilities.
We could then show that these wealth levels (and the
associated consumption choices) could also be attained in a sequential-trading
economy where there are only markets in one-period Arrow securities that reopen in each period.
In chapter \use{recurge} we also demonstrated how to obtain a
recursive formulation of the equilibrium with sequential trading.
This required us to assume that individuals' endowments
were governed by a Markov process. Under that assumption
we could identify a state vector
in terms of which the Arrow securities could be cast. This
(aggregate)
state vector then became a component of the state
vector for each individual's problem.
This transformation of price systems is easy in
the pure exchange economies of chapter \use{recurge}
because in equilibrium, the relevant state variable, wealth, is a
function solely of the
current realization of the exogenous Markov state variable.
%%%history of an exogenous Markov state variable.
The transformation is more subtle in economies in which
part of the aggregate state is endogenous in the sense that it
emerges from the
{\it history}
of
equilibrium interactions of agents' decisions. In
this chapter, we use the basic stochastic growth model (sometimes
also called the real business cycle model) as a laboratory for
moving from an equilibrium with time $0$ trading to a sequential
equilibrium with trades of Arrow securities.\NFootnote{The stochastic
growth model was formulated and fully analyzed by Brock and Mirman (1972). It
is a workhorse for studying macroeconomic fluctuations.
Kydland and Prescott (1982) used the framework to study quantitatively
the importance of persistent technology shocks for business cycle
fluctuations. Other researchers have used the stochastic
growth model as a point of departure when exploring the implications of
injecting various frictions into that otherwise frictionless environment.} %
We also formulate a
recursive competitive equilibrium with trading in Arrow securities
by using a version of
the ``Big $K$, little $k$'' device that is often used
in macroeconomics.
\index{growth model!stochastic}
\auth{Brock, William A.}
\auth{Mirman, Leonard J.}
\index{real business cycle model}
\auth{Kydland, Finn E.}
\auth{Prescott, Edward C.}
\section{The stochastic growth model}
Here we spell out the basic ingredients of the stochastic growth model:
preferences, endowment, technology, and information. The
environment is the same as in chapter \use{linappro} except
that we now allow for a stochastic technology level.
In each period $t\geq 0$, there is a realization of a stochastic
event $s_t \in S$. Let the history of events up to time $t$
be denoted $s^t = [s_t, s_{t-1}, \ldots, s_0]$. The unconditional
probability of observing a particular sequence of events $s^t$ is
given by a probability measure $\pi_t(s^t)$. We write conditional
probabilities as $\pi_\tau(s^\tau\vert s^t)$, which is the probability
of observing $s^\tau$ conditional on the realization of $s^t$.
In this chapter, we assume that the state $s_0$ in period 0 is
nonstochastic, and hence $\pi_0(s_0)=1$ for a particular
$s_0\in{\bf S}$. We use $s^t$ as a commodity space in which
goods are differentiated by histories.
A representative household has preferences over nonnegative
streams of consumption $\cst$ and leisure $\ell_t(s^t)$ that
are ordered by
$$ \sum_{t=0}^\infty \sum_{s^t} \beta^t u[\cst,\ell_t(s^t) ]\pist \EQN gr1 $$
where $\beta \in (0,1)$ and $u$ is strictly increasing in its
two arguments, twice continuously differentiable, strictly concave,
and satisfies the Inada conditions
$$
\lim_{c\to 0} u_c(c,\ell) \,=\,
\lim_{\ell\to 0} u_\ell(c,\ell) \,=\, \infty.
$$
In each period, the representative household is endowed with one
unit of time that can be devoted to leisure $\ell_t(s^t)$
or labor $\nst$:
$$ 1 = \ell_t(s^t) +\nst. \EQN gr2_endow $$
The only other endowment is a capital stock $k_0$ at the
beginning of period $0$.
The technology is
$$\EQNalign{\cst + \xst& \leq A_t(s^t) F(\kst, \nst), \EQN gr2;a \cr
\kstone & = (1-\delta) \kst + \xst, \EQN gr2;b \cr}$$
% 1 & = \ell_t(s^t) +\nst, \EQN gr2;c \cr
% \Ast & = s_0 s_1 \cdots s_t A_0 , \EQN gr2;d \cr
% &\hskip-1cm \cst, \ell_t(s^t), \nst, k_{t+1}(s^t) \geq 0,\cr
% &\hskip-1cm \hbox{\rm given} \;\, k_0.\cr}$$
where $F$ is a twice continuously differentiable,
constant-returns-to-scale production function with inputs capital
$\kst$ and labor $\nst$, and $A_t(s^t)$ is a stochastic process of
Harrod-neutral technology shocks. Outputs are the consumption good
$\cst$ and the investment good $\xst$. In \Ep{gr2;b}, the
investment good augments a capital stock that is depreciating at
the rate $\delta$. Negative values of $\xst$ are permissible, which
means that the capital stock can be reconverted into the
consumption good.
We assume that the production function satisfies standard assumptions
of positive but diminishing marginal products,
$$
F_i(k,n)>0, \quad F_{ii}(k,n)<0, \quad {\rm for}\; i=k,n;
$$
and the \idx{Inada condition}s,
$$\EQNalign{
\lim_{k\to 0}F_k(k,n) \,&=\, \lim_{n\to 0}F_n(k,n) =\infty, \cr
\lim_{k\to \infty}F_k(k,n) \,&=\, \lim_{n\to \infty}F_n(k,n) =0. \cr}
$$
Since the production function has constant returns to scale, we
can define
$$
F(k,n) \,\equiv\, n f(\hat k) \quad {\rm where} \quad
\hat k\equiv {k \over n}. \EQN ff_fratio
$$
Another property of a linearly homogeneous
function $F(k,n)$ is that its first derivatives are homogeneous of degree 0,
and thus the first derivatives are functions only of the ratio $\hat k$. In
particular, we have
$$\EQNalign{
&F_k(k,n) = {\partial \, n f\left({k / n}\right) \over \partial \, k }
= f'(\hat k), \EQN ff_partial1;a \cr
\noalign{\vskip.3cm}
&F_n(k,n) = {\partial \, n f\left({k / n}\right) \over \partial \, n }
= f(\hat k) - f'(\hat k) \hat k. \EQN ff_partial;b \cr}
$$
\section{Lagrangian formulation of the planning problem}
The planner chooses an allocation
$\{\cst, \ell_t(s^t), \xst, \nst, k_{t+1}(s^t)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}$ to
maximize \Ep{gr1} subject to \Ep{gr2_endow} and \Ep{gr2},
the initial capital stock $k_0$, and the stochastic process for the
technology level $A_t(s^t)$.
To solve this planning problem, we
form the Lagrangian
%% Ask Francois how to fix this!
\offparens
$$\eqalign{ L & = \sumst \beta^t \pist \{ u(\cst,1-\nst) \cr
&+ \must [ \Ast F(\kst,\nst)
+ (1-\delta)\kst -\cst -\kstone ]\} \cr} $$
\autoparens
where $\mu_t(s^t)$ is a process of Lagrange multipliers on
the technology constraint.
First-order conditions with respect to $\cst$, $\nst$, and $\kstone,$ respectively,
are
$$\EQNalign{ u_c(s^t) & = \must, \EQN pp1;a \cr
u_\ell(s^t) & = u_c(s^t) \Ast F_n(s^t), \EQN pp1;b \cr
u_c(s^t) \pist & = \beta \sum_{s^{t+1} \vert s^t}
u_c(s^{t+1}) \pi_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) \cr
& \hskip1cm\left[A_{t+1}(s^{t+1})
F_k(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta)\right], \EQN pp1;c \cr}$$
where the summation over
$s^{t+1} \vert s^t$ means that we sum
over all possible histories $\tilde s^{t+1}$ such that
$\tilde s^t=s^t$.
%%\section{Decentralization after Arrow-Debreu}
\section{Time $0$ trading: Arrow-Debreu securities}
In the style of Arrow and Debreu, we can support the allocation
that solves the planning problem by a competitive equilibrium with
time $0$ trading of a complete set of date- and
history-contingent securities. Trades occur among a
representative household and two types of representative
firms.\NFootnote{
One can also support the allocation that solves the planning
problem with a less decentralized setting with only the first of
our two types of firms, and in which the decision for making
physical investments is assigned to the household. We assign that
decision to a second type of firm because we want to price more
items, in particular, the capital stock.}
We let $[q^0, w^0, r^0, p_{k0}]$ be a price system where
$p_{k0}$ is the price of a unit of the initial capital stock, and
each of $q^0$, $w^0$, and $r^0$ is a stochastic process of prices for
output and for renting labor and capital, respectively, and the
time $t$ component of each is indexed by the history $s^t$. A
representative household purchases consumption goods from a type I
firm and sells labor services to the type I firm that operates
the production technology \Ep{gr2;a}.
The household owns the initial capital stock $k_0$ and at date
$0$ sells it to a type II firm. The type II firm operates the
capital storage technology \Ep{gr2;b}, purchases new investment
goods $x_{t}$ from a type I firm, and rents stocks of capital back
to the type I firm.
We now describe the problems of the
representative household and the two types of firms in the economy
with time $0$ trading.
\subsection{Household}
The household maximizes
$$ \sum_t\sum_{s^t} \beta^t u\left[\cst, 1-\nst\right]\,\pist \EQN hh1 $$
subject to
$$ \sumst \qst \cst \leq \sumst \wst \nst + p_{k0} k_0. \EQN hh2 $$
First-order conditions with respect to $\cst$ and $\nst$, respectively,
are
$$\EQNalign{ \beta^t u_c(s^t) \pist & = \eta\qst, \EQN hhh1;a \cr
\beta^t u_\ell(s^t) \pist & = \eta \wst, \EQN hhh1;b \cr}$$
where $\eta>0$ is a multiplier on the budget constraint
\Ep{hh2}.
\subsection{Firm of type I}
The representative firm of type I operates the production technology
\Ep{gr2;a}
with capital and labor that it rents at market prices. For each period
$t$ and each realization of history $s^t$, the firm enters into
state-contingent contracts at time $0$ to rent capital $k^{I}_t(s^t)$
and labor services $n_t(s^t)$. The type I firm
seeks to maximize
$$ \sumst \left\{\qst [\cst +\xst] -\rst k^I_t(s^t)
-\wst \nst \right\} \EQN fff1 $$
subject to
$$ \cst +\xst \leq \Ast F(k^I_t(s^t), \nst). \EQN fff2 $$
After substituting \Ep{fff2} into \Ep{fff1} and invoking
\Ep{ff_fratio}, the firm's objective function can be
expressed alternatively as
$$ \sumst \nst\left\{\qst \Ast f\!(\hat k^I_t(s^t))
-\rst \hat k^I_t(s^t) -\wst \right\} \hskip-.1cm\EQN fff1prime $$
and the maximization problem can then be decomposed into two parts.
First, conditional on operating the production technology
in period $t$ and history $s^t$, the firm solves for the
profit-maximizing capital-labor ratio, denoted $k^{I\star}_t(s^t)$.
Second, given that capital-labor ratio $k^{I\star}_t(s^t)$,
the firm determines the profit-maximizing level of its operation
by solving for the optimal employment level, denoted
$n^\star_t(s^t)$.
The firm finds the profit-maximizing capital-labor
ratio by maximizing the expression
in curly brackets in \Ep{fff1prime}. The first-order condition
with respect to $\hat k^{I}_t(s^t)$ is
$$ \qst \Ast f^\prime(\hat k^I_t(s^t))
-\rst = 0 \,. \EQN ff_focIk
$$
At the optimal capital-labor ratio $\hat k^{I\star}_t(s^t)$
that satisfies \Ep{ff_focIk}, the firm evaluates
the expression in curly brackets in \Ep{fff1prime} in order
to determine the optimal level of employment $n_t(s^t)$.
In particular, $n_t(s^t)$ is optimally set equal to zero or
infinity if the expression in curly brackets in \Ep{fff1prime}
is strictly negative or strictly positive, respectively. However,
if the expression in curly brackets is zero in some period $t$ and
history $s^t$, the firm would be indifferent to the level of
$n_t(s^t)$, since profits are then equal to zero for all levels of
operation in that period and state. Here, we summarize the optimal
employment decision by using equation \Ep{ff_focIk} to eliminate
$r^0_t(s^t)$ in the expression in curly brackets in \Ep{fff1prime};
$$\EQNalign{\hbox{\rm if}\hskip.2cm
&\left\{\qst \Ast \left[ f\!(\hat k^{I\star}_t(s^t))
- f^\prime(\hat k^{I\star}_t(s^t))\,\hat k^{I\star}_t(s^t)\right]
-\wst \right\} \cr
&\hskip2.5cm \cases{\,<0, &then $n^{\star}_t(s^t)=0$; \cr
\,=0, &then $n^{\star}_t(s^t)$ is indeterminate; \cr
\,>0, &then $n^{\star}_t(s^t)=\infty$. \cr}
\hskip1cm\EQN fff_nstar }
$$
In an equilibrium, both $k^{I}_t(s^t)$ and $n_t(s^t)$ are strictly positive
and finite, so expressions \Ep{ff_focIk} and \Ep{fff_nstar}
imply the following equilibrium prices:
$$\EQNalign{\qst \Ast F_k(s^t) & = \rst \EQN fff3;a \cr
\qst \Ast F_n(s^t) & = \wst \EQN fff3;b \cr} $$
where we have invoked \Ep{ff_partial1}.
\subsection{Firm of type II}
The representative firm of type II operates technology \Ep{gr2;b}
to transform output into capital. % then rents capital to a type I firm.
The type II firm purchases
capital at time
$0$ from the household sector and thereafter invests in new capital,
earning revenues by renting capital to the type I firm. It maximizes
$$ - p_{k0}k_0^{II} +
\sumst \left\{ \rst k_t^{II}(s^{t-1}) - \qst \xst \right\}
\EQN f2f1 $$
subject to
$$ k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t) = (1-\delta) k_t^{II}(s^{t-1}) + x_t(s^t). \EQN f2f2 $$
Note that the firm's capital stock in period $0$, $k_0^{II}$, is bought
without any uncertainty about the rental price in that period while
the investment in capital for a future period $t$, $k_t^{II}(s^{t-1})$,
is conditioned on the realized history $s^{t-1}$.
Thus, the type II firm manages the risk associated with technology
constraint \Ep{gr2;b} that states that capital must be assembled one
period prior to becoming an input for production.
In contrast, the type I firm of the previous
subsection can choose how much capital $k_t^{I}(s^{t})$ to rent
in period $t$ conditioned on history $s^t$.
After substituting \Ep{f2f2} into \Ep{f2f1} and rearranging,
the type II firm's objective function can be written as
$$\EQNalign{& k_0^{II}\left\{-p_{k0}
+r_0^0(s_0) + q_0^0(s_0)(1-\delta)\right\}
+ \sum_{t=0}^\infty \sum_{s^{t}} k_{t+1}^{II}(s^{t}) \cr
& \hskip.5cm \cdot\Biggl\{-q^0_{t}(s^{t})
+ \sum_{s^{t+1} \vert s^{t}} \left[r^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1})
+ q^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) (1-\delta) \right]\Biggr\} ,
\hskip1cm \EQN ff_IIk \cr}
$$
where the firm's profit is a linear function of investments in
capital. The profit-maximizing level of the capital stock
$k^{II}_{t+1}(s^{t})$ in expression \Ep{ff_IIk} is equal to
zero or infinity if the associated multiplicative term in
curly brackets is strictly negative or strictly positive,
respectively. However, for any expression in curly brackets
in \Ep{ff_IIk} that is zero, the firm would be
indifferent to the level of $k^{II}_{t+1}(s^{t})$, since profits
then equal zero for all levels of investment.
In an equilibrium, $k^{II}_0$ and $k^{II}_{t+1}(s^{t})$ are
strictly positive and finite, so each expression in curly brackets
in \Ep{ff_IIk} must equal zero, and hence equilibrium prices must satisfy
$$\EQNalign{ p_{k0} &=r_0^0(s_0) + q_0^0(s_0)(1-\delta), \EQN ffprice;a \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
q^0_{t}(s^{t})& =\sum_{s^{t+1} \vert s^{t}}
\left[r^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + q^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) (1-\delta) \right]. \EQN ffprice;b \cr}
$$
\subsection{Equilibrium prices and quantities}
According to equilibrium conditions \Ep{fff3}, each input
in the production technology is paid its marginal product,
and hence profit maximization of the type I firm ensures an efficient
allocation of labor services and capital. But nothing is said about
the equilibrium quantities of labor and capital.
Profit maximization of the type II firm imposes no-arbitrage restrictions
\Ep{ffprice} across prices $p_{k0}$ and $\{r^0_t(s^t), q^0_t(s^t)\}$.
But nothing is said about the specific equilibrium value of an
individual price. To solve for equilibrium prices and quantities, we
turn to the representative household's first-order conditions \Ep{hhh1}.
After substituting \Ep{fff3;b} into the household's first-order condition
\Ep{hhh1;b}, we obtain
$$\EQNalign{
\beta^t u_\ell(s^t) \pist &= \eta q^0_{t}(s^{t})
A_{t}(s^{t}) F_n(s^{t}) ; \EQN ff_final;a \cr
%\noalign{\vskip.3cm}
\noalign{\noindent \rm and then by substituting \Ep{ffprice;b} and
\Ep{fff3;a} into \Ep{hhh1;a},}
\noalign{\vskip.3cm}
\beta^t u_c(s^t) \pist &= \eta \sum_{s^{t+1} \vert s^{t}}
\left[r^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + q^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) (1-\delta) \right] \cr
=\eta \sum_{s^{t+1} \vert s^{t}} &q^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1})
\left[A_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) F_k(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta) \right]. \hskip1cm
\EQN ff_final;b\cr}
$$
Next, we use $q^0_t(s^t) =\beta^t u_c(s^t) \pist/\eta$ as given
by the household's first-order condition \Ep{hhh1;a} and the
corresponding expression for $q^0_{t+1}(s^{t+1})$ to substitute
into \Ep{ff_final;a} and \Ep{ff_final;b}, respectively. This step
produces expressions identical to the planner's first-order
conditions \Ep{pp1;b} and \Ep{pp1;c}, respectively. In this way,
we have verified that the allocation in the competitive
equilibrium with time $0$ trading is the same as the allocation
that solves the planning problem.
Given the equivalence of allocations, it is standard to compute
the competitive equilibrium allocation by solving the
planning problem since the latter problem is a simpler one.
We can compute equilibrium prices by substituting
the allocation from the planning problem into the household's and
firms' first-order conditions. All relative prices are then
determined, and in order to pin down absolute prices, we would also
have to pick a numeraire. Any such normalization of prices is
tantamount to setting the multiplier $\eta$ on the
household's present value budget constraint equal to an
arbitrary positive number. For example, if we set $\eta=1$,
we are measuring prices in units of marginal utility of the
time $0$ consumption good. Alternatively, we can set $q_0^0(s_0) =1$
by setting
$\eta = u_c(s_0)$. We can compute $q_t^0(s^t)$ from \Ep{hhh1;a},
$w_t^0(s^t)$ from \Ep{hhh1;b}, and $r_t^0(s^t)$ from
\Ep{fff3;a}. Finally, we can compute $p_{k0}$
from
\Ep{ffprice;a} to get
$p_{k0} = r_0^0(s_0) + q_0^0(s_0)(1-\delta)$.
\subsection{Implied wealth dynamics}
Even though trades are only executed at time $0$ in the Arrow-Debreu
market structure, we can study how the representative household's
wealth evolves over time. For that purpose, after a given
history $s^t$, we convert all prices, wages, and rental rates that
are associated with current and future deliveries so that they
are expressed in terms of time $t$, history $s^t$ consumption goods,
i.e., we change the numeraire:
$$ \EQNalign{ q^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
{q_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}
= \beta^{\tau - t} {u_c(s^\tau) \over u_c(s^t)}
\,\pi_\tau\!(s^\tau|s^t), \EQN price_renorm;a \cr
w^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
{w_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}, \EQN price_renorm;b \cr
r^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
{r_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}. \EQN price_renorm;c \cr}
$$
%$$ \EQNalign{ q^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
%{q_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}
% = \beta^{\tau - t} {u'[c_\tau(s^\tau)] \over u'[c_t(s^t)]}
% \,\pi_\tau\!(s^\tau|s^t), \EQN price_renorm;a \cr
%w^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
%{w_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}, \EQN price_renorm;b \cr
%r^t_\tau(s^\tau) &\equiv
%{r_\tau^0(s^\tau) \over q_t^0(s^t)}. \EQN price_renorm;c \cr}
%$$
In chapter \use{recurge} we asked the question, what is
the implied wealth of a household at time $t$ after history
$s^t$ when excluding the endowment stream?
Here we ask the same question except that now instead of
endowments, we exclude
the value of labor. For example, the household's net claim
to delivery of goods in a future period $\tau \geq t$,
contingent on history $s^\tau$, is given by
$[q_\tau^t(s^\tau)c_\tau(s^\tau) - w_\tau^t(s^\tau)n_\tau(s^\tau)]$,
as expressed in terms of time $t$, history $s^t$ consumption
goods. Thus, the household's wealth, or the value of all its
current and future net claims, expressed in terms of the date $t$,
history $s^t$ consumption good, is
\offparens
$$\EQNalign{
&\Upsilon_t(s^t) \equiv
\sum_{\tau=t}^\infty \; \sum_{s^\tau \vert s^t} \Bigl\{
q_\tau^t(s^\tau) c_\tau(s^\tau) - w_\tau^t(s^\tau)n_\tau(s^\tau)\Bigr\}\cr
&=
\sum_{\tau=t}^\infty \; \sum_{s^\tau \vert s^t} \Bigl\{
q_\tau^t(s^\tau) \Bigl[ A_\tau(s^\tau) F(k_\tau(s^{\tau-1}), n_\tau(s^\tau)) \cr
&\hskip4cm + (1-\delta) k_\tau(s^{\tau-1}) - k_{\tau+1}(s^\tau) \Bigr]
- w_\tau^t(s^\tau)n_\tau(s^\tau) \Bigr\}\cr
&=
\sum_{\tau=t}^\infty \; \sum_{s^\tau \vert s^t} \Bigl\{
q_\tau^t(s^\tau) \Bigl[ A_\tau(s^\tau)
\Bigl( F_k(s^\tau) k_\tau(s^{\tau-1}) + F_n(s^\tau) n_\tau(s^\tau) \Bigr) \cr
&\hskip4cm + (1-\delta) k_\tau(s^{\tau-1}) - k_{\tau+1}(s^\tau) \Bigr]
- w_\tau^t(s^\tau)n_\tau(s^\tau) \Bigr\}\cr
&=
\sum_{\tau=t}^\infty \; \sum_{s^\tau \vert s^t} \Bigl\{
r_\tau^t(s^\tau) k_\tau(s^{\tau-1}) +
q_\tau^t(s^\tau) \Bigl[ (1-\delta) k_\tau(s^{\tau-1})
- k_{\tau+1}(s^\tau) \Bigr] \Bigr\} \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
&= r_t^t(s^t) k_t(s^{t-1}) + q_t^t(s^t) (1-\delta) k_t(s^{t-1}) \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
&\hskip.5cm + \sum_{\tau=t+1}^\infty \; \sum_{s^{\tau-1} \vert s^t}
\biggl\{ \sum_{s^{\tau} \vert s^{\tau-1}}
\Bigl[r_\tau^t(s^\tau) +
q_\tau^t(s^\tau) (1-\delta) \Bigr] - q_{\tau-1}^t(s^{\tau-1}) \biggr\}
k_{\tau}(s^{\tau-1}) \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
&= \Bigl[ r_t^t(s^t) + (1-\delta) \Bigr] k_t(s^{t-1}), \EQN seq_wealth \cr}
$$
where the first equality uses the equilibrium outcome that consumption
is equal to the difference between production and investment in each period,
the second equality follows from Euler's theorem on linearly homogeneous
functions,\NFootnote{According to Euler's theorem on linearly
homogeneous functions, our constant-returns-to-scale production function
satisfies
$$
F(k,n) = F_k(k,n)\,k + F_n(k,n)\,n.
$$}
the third equality invokes equilibrium input
prices in \Ep{fff3}, the fourth equality is merely a rearrangement of
terms, and the final, fifth equality acknowledges that $q_t^t(s^t) = 1$
and that each term in curly brackets is zero because of equilibrium price
condition \Ep{ffprice;b}.
\section{Sequential trading: Arrow securities}
As in chapter \use{recurge}, we now demonstrate that sequential
trading in one-period Arrow securities provides an alternative
market structure that preserves the allocation from
the time $0$ trading equilibrium.
In the production economy with sequential trading, we
will also have to include markets for labor and capital services
that reopen in each period.
We guess that at time $t$ after history $s^t$, there exist a
wage rate $\tilde w_t(s^t)$, a rental rate $\tilde r_t(s^t)$,
and Arrow security prices $\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)$.
The {\it pricing kernel} $\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)$ is to be
interpreted as follows:
$\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)$ gives the price of one unit of
time $t+1$ consumption,
contingent on the realization $s_{t+1}$ at $t+1$, when the
history at $t$ is $s^t$.
\subsection{Household}
At each date $t \geq 0$ after history $s^t$,
the representative household buys consumption
goods $\tilde c_t(s^t)$, sells labor services $\tilde n_t(s^t)$, and
trades claims to date $t+1$ consumption,
whose payment is contingent
on the realization of $s_{t+1}$. Let $\tilde a_t(s^t)$ denote the
claims to time $t$ consumption
that the household brings into time $t$ in history $s^t$. Thus,
the household faces a sequence of budget constraints
for $t \geq 0$, where the time $t$, history $s^t$ budget constraint is
$$ \tilde c_t(s^t) + \sum_{s_{t+1}} \tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t)
\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)
\leq \tilde w_t(s^t) \tilde n_t(s^t) + \tilde a_t(s^t) , \EQN seq_hh0 $$
where
$\{\tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t)\}$ is a vector of claims on
time $t+1$ consumption,
one element of the vector for each value of the time $t+1$ realization of
$s_{t+1}$.
To rule out Ponzi schemes, we must impose borrowing constraints on
the household's asset position. We could follow the approach of
chapter \use{recurge} and compute state-contingent
{\it natural debt limits,\/} where the counterpart to the earlier present
value of the household's endowment stream would be the present
value of the household's time endowment. Alternatively, we just
impose that the household's indebtedness in any state
next period, $-\tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t)$, is bounded by some
arbitrarily large constant. Such an arbitrary debt limit works
well for the following reason. As long as the household is constrained
so that it cannot run a true Ponzi scheme with an unbounded budget
constraint, equilibrium forces will ensure that the representative
household willingly holds the market portfolio. In the present setting, we
can for example set that arbitrary debt limit equal to zero, as will
become clear as we go along.
Let $\eta_t(s^t)$ and $\nu_t(s^t;s_{t+1})$ be the nonnegative
Lagrange multipliers on the budget constraint \Ep{seq_hh0} and the
borrowing constraint with an arbitrary debt limit of zero,
respectively, for time $t$
and history $s^t$. The Lagrangian can then be formed as \offparens
$$ \eqalign{ L =
&\sum_{t=0}^\infty \sum_{s^t}
\Bigr\{ \beta^t u(\tilde c_t(s^t), 1 - \tilde n_t(s^t) ) \,\pi_t(s^t) \cr
& +\eta_t(s^t) \Bigl [\tilde w_t(s^t) \tilde n_t(s^t)
+ \tilde a_t(s^t) - \tilde c_t(s^t)
- \sum_{s_{t+1}} \tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t) \tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t) \Bigr] \cr
& +\nu_t(s^t;s_{t+1}) \tilde a_{t+1}(s^{t+1})
\Bigl\}, \cr} $$
for a given initial wealth level $\tilde a_0$. In an equilibrium,
the representative
household will choose interior solutions for
$\{\tilde c_t(s^t), \, \tilde n_t(s^t)\}_{t=0}^\infty$ because of
the assumed Inada conditions. The Inada conditions on the utility function
ensure that the household will set neither $\tilde c_t(s^t)$
nor $\ell_t(s^t)$ equal to zero, i.e., $\tilde n_t(s^t)<1$. The Inada
conditions on the production function guarantee that the
household will always find it desirable to supply some labor,
$\tilde n_t(s^t)>0$. Given these interior solutions,
the first-order conditions for maximizing $L$ with respect to
$\tilde c_t(s^t)$, $\tilde n_t(s^t)$ and
$\{\tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t)\}_{s_{t+1}}$ are
$$\EQNalign{
\beta^t u_c(\tilde c_t(s^t),1 - \tilde n_t(s^t) ) \,\pi_t(s^t)
-\eta_t(s^t) &=0\,,\EQN seq_hhFOC;a \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
-\beta^t u_\ell(\tilde c_t(s^t),1 - \tilde n_t(s^t) ) \,\pi_t(s^t)
+\eta_t(s^t) \tilde w_t(s^t) &=0\,,\EQN seq_hhFOC;b \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
-\eta_t(s^t) \tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t) + \nu_t(s^t;s_{t+1})
+ \eta_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t) &=0\,, \hskip1cm \EQN seq_hhFOC;c \cr}
$$
for all $s_{t+1}$, $t$, $s^t$. Next, we proceed under the
conjecture that the arbitrary debt limit of zero will not
be binding, and hence the Lagrange multipliers $\nu_t(s^t;s_{t+1})$
are all equal to zero. After
setting those multipliers equal to zero in equation \Ep{seq_hhFOC;c}, the
first-order conditions imply the following conditions for the
optimal choices of consumption and labor:
$$\EQNalign{
\tilde w_t(s^t) &= { u_\ell(\tilde c_t(s^t),1 - \tilde n_t(s^t) ) \over
u_c(\tilde c_t(s^t),1 - \tilde n_t(s^t) ) },
\EQN seq_hhFOCc;a \cr
\noalign{\vskip.2cm}
\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t) &= \beta
{ u_c(\tilde c_{t+1}(s^{t+1}),\, 1-\tilde n_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) ) \over
u_c(\tilde c_t(s^t),\, 1-\tilde n_t(s^t) ) }\,
\pi_t(s^{t+1} | s^t), \EQN seq_hhFOCc;b \cr}
$$
for all $t$, $s^t$, and $s_{t+1}$.
\subsection{Firm of type I}\label{sec:FirmI}%
At each date $t \geq 0$ after history $s^t$,
a type I firm is a production firm that
chooses a quadruple $\{\tilde c_t(s^t),\, \tilde x_t(s^t), \,
\tilde k_t^I(s^t),\, \tilde n_t(s^t)\}$
to solve a static optimum problem:
$$ \max\Bigl\{ \tilde c_t(s^t) + \tilde x_t(s^t)
- \tilde r_t(s^t) \tilde k^I_t(s^t)
- \tilde w_t(s^t) \tilde n_t(s^t) \Bigr\} \EQN seq_f1a $$
subject to
$$ \tilde c_t(s^t) + \tilde x_t(s^t) \leq A_t(s^t)
F( \tilde k^I_t(s^t),\, \tilde n_t(s^t) ). \EQN seq_f1b $$
The zero-profit conditions are
$$ \EQNalign{ \tilde r_t(s^t) & = A_t(s^t) F_k(s^t), \EQN seq_f1c;a \cr
\tilde w_t(s^t) & = A_t(s^t) F_n(s^t). \EQN seq_f1c;b \cr} $$
If conditions \Ep{seq_f1c} are violated, the type I firm
either makes infinite profits by hiring infinite capital
and labor, or else it makes negative profits for any positive
output level, and therefore shuts down. If conditions \Ep{seq_f1c}
are satisfied, the firm makes zero profits and its size is
indeterminate. The firm of type I is willing to produce
any quantities of $\tilde c_t(s^t)$ and $\tilde x_t(s^t)$ that the
market demands, provided
that conditions \Ep{seq_f1c} are satisfied.
\subsection{Firm of type II}\label{sec:FirmII}%
A type II firm transforms output into capital, stores capital,
and earns its revenues by renting
capital to the type I firm. Because of the technological
assumption that capital can be converted back into the consumption
good, we can without loss of generality consider a
two-period optimization problem where a type II firm decides how
much capital $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$ to store at the end of
period $t$ after history $s^t$ in order to earn a stochastic
rental revenue $\tilde r_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) \,\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$
and liquidation value $(1-\delta) \,\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$
in the following period. The firm finances itself by issuing state-contingent
debt to the households, so future income streams can
be expressed in today's values by using prices
$\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)$. Thus, at each date $t \geq 0$ after
history $s^t$, a type II firm chooses $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$
to solve the optimum problem
$$ \max \; \tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t) \Bigl\{ -1 +
\sum_{s_{t+1}} \tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)
\left[ \tilde r_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta)
\right]\Bigr\} . \EQN seq_f2a $$
The zero-profit condition is
$$ 1 = \sum_{s_{t+1}} \tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)
\Bigl[ \tilde r_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta)
\Bigr]. \EQN seq_f2b $$
The size of the type II firm is indeterminate.
So long as condition \Ep{seq_f2b} is satisfied, the firm breaks even
at any level of $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$.
If condition \Ep{seq_f2b} is not satisfied, either it
can earn infinite profits by setting $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$
to be arbitrarily large (when
the right side exceeds the left),
or it earns negative profits for any positive level of capital (when
the right side falls short of the left), and
so chooses to shut down.
\subsection{Equilibrium prices and quantities}
We leave it to the reader to follow the approach taken in
chapter \use{recurge} to show the equivalence of
allocations attained in the sequential equilibrium and the
time $0$ equilibrium,
$\{\tilde c_t(s^t), \tilde \ell_t(s^t), \tilde x_t(s^t),
\tilde n_t(s^t), \tilde k_{t+1}(s^t)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}=
\{\cst, \ell_t(s^t), \xst, $ $\nst, k_{t+1}(s^t)\}_{t=0}^{\infty}$.
The trick is to guess that the prices in the sequential
equilibrium satisfy
$$ \EQNalign{\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t) &= q^t_{t+1}(s^{t+1}),\EQN price_seq;a \cr
\tilde w_t(s^t) &= w_t^t(s^t), \EQN price_seq;b \cr
\tilde r_t(s^t) &= r_t^t(s^t). \EQN price_seq;c \cr}
$$
The other set of guesses is that the representative household
chooses asset portfolios given by
$\tilde a_{t+1}(s_{t+1},s^t) = \Upsilon_{t+1}(s^{t+1})$ for all
$s_{t+1}$. When showing that the household can afford these asset
portfolios together with the prescribed quantities of consumption
and leisure, we will find that the required initial wealth is equal to
$$
\tilde a_0 = [r^0_0(s_0) + (1-\delta) ] k_0 = p_{k0} k_0,
$$
i.e., the household in the sequential equilibrium starts out
at the beginning of period $0$ owning
the initial capital stock, which is then sold to a type II firm at the
same competitive price as in the time $0$ trading equilibrium.
\subsection{Financing a type II firm}
A type II firm finances purchases of $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$
units of capital in period $t$ after history $s^t$ by issuing
one-period state-contingent claims that promise
to pay
$$\left[ \tilde r_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta) \right]
\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$$
consumption goods tomorrow in state
$s_{t+1}$. In units of today's time $t$ consumption good,
these payouts are worth \hfil\break
$$\sum_{s_{t+1}} \tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t)
\left[ \tilde r_{t+1}(s^{t+1}) + (1-\delta) \right]
\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$$
(by virtue of \Ep{seq_f2b}).
The firm breaks even by issuing these claims.
Thus, the firm of type II is entirely owned by its creditor, the
household, and it earns zero profits.
Note that the economy's end-of-period wealth as embodied
in $\tilde k_{t+1}^{II}(s^t)$ in period $t$ after history $s^t$
is willingly held by the representative household. This follows
immediately from fact that the household's desired
beginning-of-period wealth next period is given by
$\tilde a_{t+1}(s^{t+1})$ and is equal to $\Upsilon_{t+1}(s^{t+1})$,
as given by \Ep{seq_wealth}. Thus, the equilibrium prices entice the
representative household to enter each future period with
a strictly positive net asset level that is equal to the value
of the type II firm. We have then confirmed the correctness
of our earlier conjecture that the arbitrary
debt limit of zero is not binding in the household's optimization
problem.
\section{Recursive formulation}
Following the approach taken in chapter \use{recurge},
we have established that the
equilibrium allocations are the same in the Arrow-Debreu
economy with complete markets at time $0$ and in a
sequential-trading economy with complete one-period
Arrow securities. This finding holds for an arbitrary
technology process $A_t(s^t)$, defined as a measurable
function of the history of events $s^t$ which in turn are
governed by some arbitrary probability measure $\pi_t(s^t)$.
At this level of generality,
all prices $\{\tilde Q_t(s_{t+1} | s^t),\, \tilde w_t(s^t),\,
\tilde r_t(s^t)\}$ and the capital stock $k_{t+1}(s^t)$
in the
sequential-trading economy depend on the history $s^t$. That is,
these objects are time-varying functions of all past events
$\{s_\tau\}_{\tau=0}^t$.
In order to obtain a recursive formulation and solution to both the
social planning problem and the sequential-trading equilibrium,
we make the following specialization of the
exogenous forcing process for the technology level.
\subsection{Technology is governed by a Markov process}
Let the stochastic event $s_t$ be governed by a Markov process,
$[s\in {\bf S}, \pi(s'|s),$ $\pi_0(s_0)]$. We keep our earlier
assumption that the state $s_0$ in period 0 is
nonstochastic and hence $\pi_0(s_0)=1$ for a particular
$s_0\in{\bf S}$. The sequences of probability measures $\pi_t(s^t)$
on histories $s^t$ are induced by the Markov
process via the recursions
$$ \pi_t(s^t) = \pi(s_t | s_{t-1}) \pi(s_{t-1} | s_{t-2}) \ldots
\pi(s_1 | s_0) \pi_0(s_0). $$
Next, we assume that the aggregate technology level $A_t(s^t)$
in period $t$ is a time-invariant measurable function of its
level in the last period and the current stochastic event $s_t$,
i.e., $A_t(s^t) = A\left( A_{t-1}(s^{t-1}),\, s_t\right)$. For
example, here we will proceed with the multiplicative version
$$
A_t(s^t) = s_t A_{t-1}(s^{t-1}) = s_0 \,s_1 \cdots s_t \, A_{-1},
$$
given the initial value $A_{-1}$.
\subsection{Aggregate state of the economy}
The specialization of the technology process enables us to
adapt the recursive construction of chapter \use{recurge} to incorporate
additional components of the state of the economy. Besides information
about the current value of the stochastic event $s$, we need to know
last period's technology level, denoted $A$, in order to determine
current technology level, $s\,A$, and to forecast future technology
levels. This additional element $A$ in the aggregate state vector
does not constitute any conceptual change from what we did in
chapter \use{recurge}. We are merely including one more state
variable that is a direct mapping from exogenous stochastic events,
and it does not depend on any endogenous outcomes.
But we also need to expand the aggregate state vector with
an endogenous component of the state of the economy, namely, the
beginning-of-period capital stock $K$. Given the new state
vector $X\equiv \left[ K \; A \; s\right]$, we are ready to
explore recursive formulations of both the planning problem
and the sequential-trading equilibrium. This state vector is
a complete summary of the economy's current position. It is
all that is needed for a planner to compute an optimal
allocation and it is all that is needed for the ``invisible hand''
to call out prices and implement the first-best
allocation as a competitive equilibrium.
We proceed as follows. First, we display the Bellman equation
associated with a recursive formulation of the planning problem. Second, we
use the
same state vector $X$
for the planner's problem as a state vector
in which to cast the Arrow securities in a competitive economy with sequential
trading. Then we define a competitive equilibrium
and show how the prices for the sequential equilibrium are embedded in
the decision rules and the value function of the planning problem.
%We want to decentralize the solution of the planning problem via
%a competitive equilibrium with sequential trading in current period
%commodities and one-period Arrow securities. Accomplishing this requires
%that we adapt the construction of chapter \use{recurge} to incorporate
%an endogenous component of the state of the economy, namely, the
%capital stock.
%We proceed as follows. First, we display the Bellman equation
%associated with a recursive formulation of the planning problem. We
%use the state vector for the planner's problem to define a state vector
%in which to cast the Arrow securities in a competitive economy with sequential
%trading. Then we define a competitive equilibrium
%and show how the prices for the sequential equilibrium are embedded in
%the decision rules and the value function of the planning problem.
\section{Recursive formulation of the planning problem}
We use capital letters $C,N,K$ to denote objects in the planning problem
that correspond to $c,n,k$, respectively, in the household's and firms'
problems. We shall eventually equate them, but not until we have
derived an appropriate formulation of the household's and firms' problems
in a recursive competitive equilibrium.
The Bellman equation for the planning problem is
$$ v(K,A,s) = \max_{C,N, K'} \left\{ u(C,1-N)
+\beta \sum_{s'} \pi(s'|s) v(K', A', s') \right\} \EQN plan1 $$
subject to
$$\EQNalign{ K' + C & \leq A s F(K, N) + (1-\delta )K , \EQN plan2;a \cr
A' & = A s. \EQN plan2;b \cr} $$
Using the definition of the state vector
$X = \left[ K \; A \; s\right]$, we denote the optimal
policy functions as
$$ \EQNalign{ C & = \Omega^C(X), \EQN plan3;a \cr
N & = \Omega^N(X), \EQN plan3;b \cr
K' & = \Omega^K(X) . \EQN plan3;c \cr} $$
Equations \Ep{plan2;b}, \Ep{plan3;c}, and the Markov transition
density $\pi(s'|s)$ induce a transition density $\Pi(X'|X)$ on the
state $X$.
For convenience, define the functions
$$ \EQNalign{ U_c(X) & \equiv u_c(\Omega^C(X), 1 - \Omega^N(X)), \EQN plan4;a \cr
U_\ell(X) & \equiv u_\ell(\Omega^C(X), 1 - \Omega^N(X)), \EQN plan4;b \cr
F_k(X) & \equiv F_k(K, \Omega^N(X)), \EQN plan4;c \cr
F_n(X) & \equiv F_n(K, \Omega^N(X)). \EQN plan4;d \cr}$$
The first-order conditions for the planner's problem can be represented
as\NFootnote{We are using the envelope condition
$$v_K(K,A,s) = U_c(X)[A s F_k(X) +(1-\delta)].$$}%
$$ \EQNalign{ U_\ell(X) & = U_c(X) A s F_n(X), \EQN plan5;a \cr
1& = \beta \sum_{X'} \Pi(X'| X) {U_c(X') \over U_c(X)}
[A' s' F_K(X') + (1-\delta)]. \hskip1cm \EQN
plan5;b \cr} $$
\section{Recursive formulation of sequential trading}\label{sec:bigKlittlek}%
We seek a competitive equilibrium with sequential trading of
one-period-ahead state-contingent securities (i.e., Arrow securities).
To do this, we must use a ``Big $K$, little $k$'' trick of the type used in
chapter \use{recurpe}. \index{Big $K$, little $k$}%
\subsection{A ``Big $K$, little $k$'' device}
Relative to the setup described in chapter \use{recurge}, we have
augmented the time $t$ state of the economy by both last period's
technology level $A_{t-1}$ and the current aggregate value of
the endogenous state variable $K_t$. We assume that decision
makers act as if their decisions do not affect current or future prices. In a
sequential market setting, prices depend on the state, of which
$K_t$ is part. Of course, {\it in the aggregate\/}, decision